Since 2018, the U. S. Government has launched a massive trade war, so it is necessary to reveal its ideological and historical root. We use the form evolution of American mercantilism as clues to do it. When comparing it with the classical form of mercantilism which was popular in Europe from the 16th to 18th century, we find that American mercantilism has evolved from the traditional form to the new form. The traditional form of American mercantilism existed mainly in the era of the rise (before 1913). In the era, mercantilists inherited the traditional thought from British mercantilists; on the other hand, according to the socioeconomic status and geopolitical environment, American politicians put forward a set of economic development strategy, which was first proposed by Alexander Hamilton, then put forward by Henry Clay. It can be summed up as the " American System”, which consists of three mutually reinforcing parts: tariff protection, internal improvement and the national bank. Among them, the tariff protection policy is the most important one, by which the United States has achieved the industrialization path driven by domestic demand (Jia Genliang et al., 2017), so trade protectionism has become a national memory in the United States. Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods System in 1971, American mercantilism has developed its new form. Compared with the classical form, the new form is really a distorted expression. On the one hand, trade deficit has become a main fulcrum to maintain dollar hegemony, while the classical form emphasizes on trade surplus. On the other hand, dollar hegemony becomes the main means of depriving other countries’ wealth. Although one is in the era of metal currency, the other in the era of credit currency, dollar hegemonism is largely as same as bullionism in essence, which is the earlier form of classical mercantilism. Nowadays, " double deficits” or the coexistence of trade deficit and fiscal deficit is the most important feature in American economy, and the trade protection policy is the most important means to maintain American hegemony. Historically, there is a deep economic strategy root for the evolution of American mercantilism. In the era of the rise, the United States hoped its national strength can be improved through the development of manufactures by the tariff protection policy and domestic market competition. Since 1971, the United States hoped its dollar hegemony can be recast to intensify American hegemony, so a series of abnormal economic policies and phenomena appeared. Since then, despite the form of American mercantilism has changed completely, the old ideas in classical mercantilism such as " zero-sum game” are still in vogue because of the strategic demand of American hegemony. The above analysis implies that the United States would take such strategic actions as a trade war to suppress its most important strategic rivals, while it inevitably incurs the result of " lose-lose”.
/ Journals / Journal of Finance and Economics
Journal of Finance and Economics
LiuYuanchun, Editor-in-Chief
ZhengChunrong, Vice Executive Editor-in-Chief
YaoLan BaoXiaohua HuangJun, Vice Editor-in-Chief
The Root of American Trade Protectionism:Using its Form Evolution of Mercantilism as Clues
Journal of Finance and Economics Vol. 44, Issue 12, pp. 18 - 30 (2018) DOI:10.16538/j.cnki.jfe.2018.12.002
Summary
References
Summary
[1]Chen B S. Debt economy in the United States and unbalance of the global economy[J]. Forum of World Economy and Politics, 2007, (3): 1-8. (In Chinese)
[2]Hobsbawm E. Industry and empire: From 1750 to the present day[M]. Translated by Mei J J. Beijing: Central Compilation & Translation Press, 2013. (In Chinese)
[3]Jefferson T. The selected writings of Thomas Jefferson[M]. Translated by Zhu C W. Beijing: The Commercial Press, 2012. (In Chinese)
[4]Jia G L. American school and the industrialization path driven by domestic demand in the United States in 19th century[M]. Beijing: People’s University of China Press, 2017. (In Chinese)
[5]Kennedy P. The rise and fall of the great powers[M]. Translated by Wang B C et al.. Beijing: China CITIC Press, 2013. (In Chinese)
[6]Li C. The establishment of supra sovereign international money: The reform of international monetary system[M]. Beijing: Beijing Normal University Publishing Group, 2014. (In Chinese)
[7]Li X K. State and market of British mercantilism of historical interpretation[M]. Beijing: Central Compilation & Translation Press, 2013. (In Chinese)
[8]List F. The national system of political economy[M]. Translated by Chen W X. Beijing: The Commercial Press, 1994. (In Chinese)
[9]Liu Z K. The reform and adjustment of post-cold war American export control policy[J]. American Studies Quarterly, 2008, (2): 107-127. (In Chinese)
[10]Mei J J. A reassessment of mercantilism in historical perspective[J]. Journal of Social Sciences, 2017, (7): 123-144. (In Chinese)
[11]Qian Z D. World history research should focus on the discussion and decision of the important issues: Also on the select of topic and perspective[N]. Guangming Daily, February 6, 2017. (In Chinese)
[12]Shen G B. U. S. export controls and the issue of the Sino-U.S. trade balance[J]. World Economics and Politics, 2006, (3): 71-77. (In Chinese)
[13]Sheng B, Li D X. Global trade protectionism after the financial crisis and the improvement of WTO rules[J]. International Economics and Trade Research, 2010, (10): 22-27. (In Chinese)
[14]Smith A. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations[M]. Translated by Guo D L et al.. Beijing: The Commercial Press, 1994. (In Chinese)
[15]Wang L X. Hesitating hegemony: Identity confusion and order pursuit after the rise of the United States (1913-1945)[M]. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press, 2015. (In Chinese)
[16]Wang X D. The economic nationalism and its influence in the early American history[J]. Nankai Journal, 2006, (1): 18-26. (In Chinese)
[17]Wu S L. Economic thoughts of the rise of the great powers: On Hamilton’s contributions from his three national reports[N]. Shanghai Wenhui Daily, June 17, 2016. (In Chinese)
[18]Wu S L. China’s market economy status and mercantilism tradition in American, European, and Japanese[N]. Shanghai Wenhui Daily, January 20, 2017. (In Chinese)
[19]Wu S L. How to explain and solve the Sino-U.S. trade friction from a strategic height[J]. Intertrade, 2018, (6): 34-38. (In Chinese)
[20]Zhao K. The rise of Deutsche Mark: the political economy analysis on currency internationalization[M]. Beijing: Central Compilation & Translation Press, 2015. (In Chinese)
[21]Zhao N T. History of European and American economics[M]. Beijing: Oriente Publishing House, 2007. (In Chinese)
[22]Zheng T Q, Le H. The special mercantilism thoughts in the early American history[J]. Wuhan University Journal (Humanity), 2012, (2): 96-103. (In Chinese)
[23]Bureau of the Census. Historical statistics of the United States: Colonial times to 1970 (Part 2)[M]. Washington, DC: University of Michigan Library, 1975.
[24]Dales J H. The discoveries and mercantilism: An essay in history and theory[J]. The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 1955, 21(2): 141-153.
[25]Hamilton A, Madison J, Jay J. The federalist papers[M]. New York: Clinton Lawrence, 1961.
[26]Huckster E F. Mercantilism (VOL. II)[M]. New York: Carland Publishing Inc., 1983.
[27]Irwin D A. New estimates of the average tariff of the United States, 1790-1820[J]. The Journal of Economic History, 2003, 63(2): 506-513.
[28]Judzik D. Heterogeneous labor demand: Sectoral elasticity and trade effects in the U.S., Germany and Sweden[R]. MPRA Paper No. 62768, 2015.
[29]Nettels C P. British mercantilism and the economic development of the thirteen colonies[J]. Journal of Economic History, 1952, 12(2): 105-114.
[30]Taussig F W. The tariff history of the United States[M]. New York: G.P. Putnam’s Sons, 1888.
[31]Viner J. Power versus plenty as objectives of foreign policy in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries[J]. World Politics, 1948, 1(1): 1-29.
[32]Williams W A. The age of mercantilism: An interpretation of the American political economy, 1763 to 1828[J]. The William and Mary Quarterly, 1958, 15(4): 419-437.
[33]Wilson C. Treasure and trade balances: The mercantilist problem[J]. The Economic History Review, 1949, 2(2): 152-161.
[34]Wilson C. Mercantilism[M]. London: The Historical Association, 1971.
[35]Yanikkaya H. Is trade liberalization a solution to the unemployment problem?[J]. Portuguese Economic Journal, 2013, 12(1): 57-85.
Cite this article
Wu Shanlin. The Root of American Trade Protectionism:Using its Form Evolution of Mercantilism as Clues[J]. Journal of Finance and Economics, 2018, 44(12): 18-30.
Export Citations as:
For
Previous: The Spillover Effects of Venture Capital
ISSUE COVER
RELATED ARTICLES