[1] Bao X H. Has China encountered discriminatory anti-dumping: Comparing with other exporters[J]. Management World, 2011, (3): 32-43. (In Chinese)
[2] Dai M, Xu J W, Shi B Z. The shocks from the exchange rate of RMB, and the employment in manufacturing industry: The experience evidence from the data on firms[J]. Management World, 2013, (11): 14-27. (In Chinese)
[3] Fan H C, Guo G Y. Export price, export quality and productivity: Evidence from China[J]. Journal of World Economy, 2015, (2): 58-85. (In Chinese)
[4] Li C D, Shi X J, Fei T A. Antidumping promotes productivity: Chinese evidence and explanation[J]. Finance and Trade Economics, 2013, (7): 68-78. (In Chinese)
[5] Liu X N, Liu L. Effects of trade liberalization on quality of export products: An empirical research based on China’s micro manufacturing enterprise[J]. Journal of International Trade, 2015, (8):14-23. (In Chinese)
[6] Shen G B. The trade effect of the U.S. anti-dumping against China: An empirical analysis based on wooden bedroom furniture[J]. Management World, 2008, (4): 48-57. (In Chinese)
[7] Shi B Z. The product quality heterogeneity of China firm’s export: Measurement and facts[J]. China Economic Quarterly, 2014, (1): 263-284. (In Chinese)
[8] Shi B Z, Zhang Y R. Trade liberalization and quality upgrading of Chinese firm’s imported intermediate products[J]. Journal of Quantitative and Technical Economics, 2016, (9): 3-21. (In Chinese)
[9] Song H S, Zhu X M. Chinese anti-dumping protection and manufacturing firm’s markups[J]. Journal of International Trade, 2017, (12): 94-107. (In Chinese)
[10] Su Z D, Shao Y. Can anti-dumping measures improve performances of Chinese firms? A case study of “Bisphenol A”[J]. Economic Review, 2013, (4): 81-87. (In Chinese)
[11] Su Z D, Shao Y. Can anti-dumping measures survival rate of Chinese firms? A case study of chemical product “Bisphenol A”[J]. Finance and Trade Economics, 2014, (9): 82-93. (In Chinese)
[12] Wang J X. Trade liberalization, quality gaps and quality upgrading of regional exports[J]. Journal of International Trade, 2014, (10): 3-13. (In Chinese)
[13] Wang X S, Shi B Z, Xie S X, Zhao C M. How do trade barriers affect dual margins of China’s export growth?[J]. Economic Research Journal, 2014, (11): 58-71. (In Chinese)
[14] Wang X S, Zhai G Y, Lin F Q. A study on the inhibitory effect of anti-dumping on China’s exports[J]. Journal of World Economy, 2015, (5): 36-58. (In Chinese)
[15] Xie J G, Zhang S Z. Anti-dumping and the quality upgrading of China’s export products: An empirical study based on US-China anti-dumping database[J]. Journal of International Trade, 2017, (1): 153-164. (In Chinese)
[16] Yu M J, Li L R. Trade liberalization and quality upgrading of intermediate inputs: Evidence from Chinese customs data[J]. China Economic Quarterly, 2016, (3): 1012-1028. (In Chinese)
[17] Amiti M, Khandelwal A K. Import competition and quality upgrading[J]. Review of Economics and Statistics, 2013, 95(2): 476-490. DOI:10.1162/REST_a_00271
[18] Amiti M, Konings J. Trade liberalization, intermediate inputs, and productivity: Evidence from Indonesia[J]. American Economic Review, 2007, 97(5): 1611-1638. DOI:10.1257/aer.97.5.1611
[19] Aw B Y, Roberts M J. Measuring quality change in quota-constrained import markets: The case of U.S. footwear[J]. Journal of International Economics, 1986, 21(1-2): 45-60. DOI:10.1016/0022-1996(86)90004-8
[20] Baldwin R, Harrigan J. Zeros, quality, and space: Trade theory and trade evidence[J]. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2011, 3(2): 60-88. DOI:10.1257/mic.3.2.60
[21] Bas M, Strauss-Kahn V. Input-trade liberalization, export prices and quality upgrading[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2015, 95(2): 250-262. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2014.12.005
[22] Boorstein R, Feenstra R C. Quality upgrading and its welfare cost in U.S. steel imports, 1969-74[A]. Helpman E, Razin A. International trade and trade policy[M]. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991.
[23] Bown C P, Crowley M A. Trade deflection and trade depression[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2007, 72(1): 176-201. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.09.005
[24] Broda C, Weinstein D E. Globalization and the gains from variety[J]. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2006, 121(2): 541-585. DOI:10.1162/qjec.2006.121.2.541
[25] Correia S. REGHDFE: Stata module to perform linear or instrumental-variable regression absorbing any number of high-dimensional fixed effects[EB/OL]. https://econpapers.repec.org/software/bocbocode/S457874.htm, 2018.
[26] De Loecker J, Goldberg P K, Khandelwal A K, et al. Prices, markups, and trade reform[J]. Econometrica, 2016, 84(2): 445-510. DOI:10.3982/ECTA11042
[27] Falvey R E. The composition of trade within import-restricted product categories[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 1979, 87(5): 1105-1114. DOI:10.1086/260814
[28] Fan H C, Li Y A, Yeaple S R. Trade liberalization, quality, and export prices[J]. Review of Economics and Statistics, 2015, 97(5): 1033-1051. DOI:10.1162/REST_a_00524
[29] Fan H C, Li Y A, Yeaple S R. On the relationship between quality and productivity: Evidence from China’s accession to the WTO[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2018, 110: 28-49. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2017.10.001
[30] Feenstra R C. Voluntary export restraint in U.S. autos, 1980-81: Quality, employment, and welfare effects[A]. Baldwin R E, Krueger A O. The structure and evolution of recent U.S. trade policy[C]. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984.
[31] Feenstra R C. Quality change under trade restraints in Japanese autos[J]. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1988, 103(1): 131-146. DOI:10.2307/1882645
[32] Feng L, Li Z Y, Swenson D L. The connection between imported intermediate inputs and exports: Evidence from Chinese firms[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2016, 101: 86-101. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2016.03.004
[33] Goldberg P K. Trade policies in the U.S. automobile industry[J]. Japan and the World Economy, 1994, 6(2): 175-208. DOI:10.1016/0922-1425(94)00013-1
[34] Goldberg P K. Product differentiation and oligopoly in international markets: The case of the U.S. automobile industry[J]. Econometrica, 1995, 63(4): 891-951. DOI:10.2307/2171803
[35] Hallak J C. Product quality and the direction of trade[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2006, 68(1): 238-265. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.04.001
[36] Hummels D, Klenow P J. The variety and quality of a nation’s exports[J]. American Economic Review, 2005, 95(3): 704-723. DOI:10.1257/0002828054201396
[37] Johnson R C. Trade and prices with heterogeneous firms[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2012, 86(1): 43-56. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.09.004
[38] Khandelwal A K, Schott P K, Wei S J. Trade liberalization and embedded institutional reform: Evidence from Chinese exporters[J]. American Economic Review, 2013, 103(6): 2169-2195. DOI:10.1257/aer.103.6.2169
[39] Konings J, Vandenbussche H. Heterogeneous responses of firms to trade protection[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2008, 76(2): 371-383. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2008.08.002
[40] Konings J, Vandenbussche H, Springael L. Import diversion under European antidumping policy[J]. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 2001, 1(3): 283-299. DOI:10.1023/A:1015269804381
[41] Krishna K. Tariffs versus quotas with endogenous quality[J]. Journal of International Economics, 1987, 23(1−2): 97-122. DOI:10.1016/S0022-1996(87)80007-7
[42] Krishna K. Protection and the product line: Monopoly and product quality[J]. International Economic Review, 1990, 31(1): 87-102. DOI:10.2307/2526630
[43] Kugler M, Verhoogen E. Prices, plant size, and product quality[J]. The Review of Economic Studies, 2012, 79(1): 307-339. DOI:10.1093/restud/rdr021
[44] Lu Y, Tao Z G, Zhang Y. How do exporters respond to antidumping investigations?[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2013, 91(2): 290-300. DOI:10.1016/j.jinteco.2013.08.005
[45] Pavcnik N. Trade liberalization, exit, and productivity improvements: Evidence from Chilean plants[J]. The Review of Economic Studies, 2002, 69(1): 245-276. DOI:10.1111/1467-937X.00205
[46] Ries J C. Voluntary export restraints, profits, and quality adjustment[J]. Canadian Journal of Economics, 1993, 26(3): 688-706. DOI:10.2307/135895
[47] Rodriguez C A. The quality of imports and the differential welfare effects of tariffs, quotas, and quality controls as protective devices[J]. Canadian Journal of Economics, 1979, 12(3): 439-449. DOI:10.2307/134732
[48] Romalis J. Market access, openness and growth[R]. NBER Working Paper No.w13048, 2007.
[49] Russo J E. The human cost: A comment on dardis[J]. Journal of Consumer Policy, 1987, 10(1): 89-92. DOI:10.1007/BF00411947
[50] Schott P K. Across-product versus within-product specialization in international trade[J]. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2004, 119(2): 647-678. DOI:10.1162/0033553041382201
[51] Topalova P, Khandelwal A. Trade liberalization and firm productivity: The case of India[J]. Review of Economics and Statistics, 2011, 93(3): 995-1009. DOI:10.1162/REST_a_00095
[52] Vandenbussche H, Wauthy X. Inflicting injury through product quality: How European antidumping policy disadvan- tages European producers[J]. European Journal of Political Economy, 2001, 17(1): 101-116. DOI:10.1016/S0176-2680(00)00030-6
[53] Verhoogen E A. Trade, quality upgrading, and wage inequality in the Mexican manufacturing sector[J]. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2008, 123(2): 489-530. DOI:10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.489